Abstract
Abstract. This research develops a model of eligible voters rationally maximizing their stochastic utility functions in their decisions with respect to casting ballots in elections that result in voting decision being largely determined by social and psychological factors heterogeneously maleable by political expenditures. The wealthiest agents utilize their overwhelming financial resources to promote only candidates cooperating with their special interests to attract public attention, which exerts social pressure on voters to cast ballots only for those politicians who represent those agents. The model, which enables exacting computation of the benefits to politicians, special interest groups, and voters from their political actions, is shown to supply insightful explanations for the 2016 U.S. Presidential polling results for the four leading candidates. Voters were effectively swayed by large political expenditures to select from the two candidates who represented the agents providing the financial backing to market their special interests.
Keywords. Special interests, Voter utility, Elections, Political marketing.
JEL. D71, D72, F50.References
Addoum, J., Delikouras, S., Ke, D., & Kumar, A. (2018). Underreaction to Political Information and Price Momentum. Financial Management, 48(3), 773-804. doi. 10.1111/fima.12241
Aggarwal, R., Meschke, F., & Wang, T. (2012). Corporate political donations: Investment or agency?” Business and Politics 14(1), 1-39. doi. 10.1515/1469-3569.1391
Agiesta, J. (2016). Poll: Clinton tops Trump, but neither prompts excitement. CNN, June 21. [Retrieved from].
Altomonte, C., Gennaro, G., & Passareli, F. (2019). Collective emotions and protest vote. SSRN paper, [Retrieved from].
Ansolabehere, S., Figueiredo, J., & Snyder, J. (2003). Why is ther so little money in U.S. politics. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1), 105-130. doi. 10.1257/089533003321164976
Ansolabehere, S., & Snyder, J. (2000). Valence politics and equilibrium in spatial election models. Public Choice, 103(3-4), 327-336. doi. 10.1023/A:1005020606153
Babenko, I., Fedaseyeu, V., & Zhang, S. (2017). Executives in politics, SSRN Papers. [Retrieved from].
Baron, D. (1994). Electoral competition with informed and uninformed voters. American Political Science Review, 63(2), 265-286. doi. 10.2307/2297852
Bassetti, T., & Pavesi, F. (2017). Electoral contributions and the cost of unpopularity. Economic Inquiry, 55(4), 1755-1791. doi. 10.1111/ecin.12461
Becker, J., Tausch, N., & Wagner, U. (2011). Emotional consequences of collective action participation: Differentiating self-directed and outgroup-directed emotions. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 37(2), 1587-1598. doi. 10.1177/0146167211414145
Bombardini, M., & Trebbi, F. (2011). Votes or money? Evidence from the U.S. congress. Journal of Public Economics, 95(7-8), 587-611. doi. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2010.11.018
Bouton, L., Castanheira, M., & Saguer, A. (2017). Multicandidate elections: Aggregate uncertainty in the laboratory. Games and Economic Behavior, 101, 132-150. doi. 10.1016/j.geb.2015.10.003
Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1984). Voter choice. American Behavioral Scientist, 28(2), 185-201. doi. 10.1177/000276484028002003
Boyer, P. (2018). It's the economy stupid. NewScientist, September 22, 40-43.
Cardy, E. (2005). An experimental field study of the GOTV and persuasion effects of partisan direct mail and phone calls. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 60, 28-40.
Churchwell, S. (2018). Behold, America: the Engtangled History of America First. Basic Books: New York.
Coate, S., & Conlin, M. (2004). A group rule: Utilitarian approach to voter turnout: Theory and evidence. American Economic Review, 94(5), 1476-1504. doi. 10.1257/0002828043052231
Congleton, R. (2018). On the emergence of a classic work: A short history of the impact of Gordon Tullock's 'Welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft'”, Public Choice, 181(1-2), 5-12. doi. 10.1007/s11127-018-0542-4
Cooper, M., Gulen, H., & Ovtchinnovkov, A. (2010). Corporate political contributions and stock returns. Journal of Finance, 65(2), 687-724. doi. 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01548.x
Dellis, M. (2013). The two-party system under alternative voting procedures. Social Choice and Welfare, 40(1), 263-284. doi. 10.1007/s00355-011-0597-3
Di Tella, R., & Rotenberg, J. (2018). Populism and the return of the 'Paranoid Style': Some evidence and a simple model of demand for incompetence as insurance against Elite Betrayal. Journal of Comparative Economics, 46(4), 988-1005. doi. 10.1016/j.jce.2018.03.001
Dowling, C., & Wichowsky, A. (2013). Does it matter who's behind the curtain? Anonymity in political advertising and the effects of campaign finance disclosure. American Politics Research, 41(6), 965-996. doi. 10.1177/1532673X13480828
Dyck, A., Moss, D., & Zingales, L. (2013). Media versus special interests. Journal of Law & Economics, 56(3), 521-553. doi. 10.1086/673216
Dsouza, D. (2019). The green new deal explained. Investopedia, March 6. [Retrieved from].
Economist. (2017a). The point of patouflage. September 16. 64.
Economist. (2017b). Half of democracy is showing up. November 18. 31.
Faravelli, M., Kalavci, K., & Pimienta, C. (2017). Costly voting: A large-scale real effort experiment. SSRN Working paper, [Retrieved from].
Feddersen, T., & Sandroni, A. (2006). A theory of participation in elections. American Economic Review, 96(4), 1271-1282. doi. 10.1257/aer.96.4.1271
Fergusson, L. (2014). Media markets, special interests, and voters. Journal of Public Economics, 109, 13-26. doi. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2013.10.007
Fey, M. (1997). Stability and coordination in Duverger's law: A formal model of preelection polls and strategic voting. American Political Science Review, 91(1), 135-147. doi. 10.2307/2952264
Fisher, S., & Myatt, D. (2016). Strategic voting in plurality rule elections. Stanford Working Paper, [Retrieved from].
Forand, J., & Maheshri, V. (2015). A dynamic Daverger's law. Public Choice, 165(3), 285-306. doi. 10.1007/s11127-016-0309-8
Gaffney, A., Hackett, J., Rast, D.III., Hohman, Z., & Jaurique, A. (2018). The state of American protest: Shraed anger and populism. Analyses of Social Issues and Public Policy, 18(1), 11-33. doi. 10.1111/asap.12145
Gerber, D., Green, D., & Larmer, C. (2008). Social pressure and voter turnout: Evidence from a large-scale field experiment. American Political Science Review, 102(1), 33-48. doi. 10.1017/S000305540808009X
Gigenrenzer, G. (2007). Gut Feelings: The Intelligence of the Subconscious. Viking: New York.
Green, D., & Krasno, J. (1988). Salvation for the incumbents: Re-estimating the effects of campaign spending in house elections. American Journal of Political Science, 32(4), 884-907. doi. 10.2307/2111193
Green, D., McGrath, M., & Aronow, P. (2013). Field experiments and the study of voter Turnout. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties, 23(1), 27-48. doi. 10.1080/17457289.2012.728223
Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1996). Electoral competition and special interest politics. Review of Economic Studies, 63(2), 265-286. doi. 10.2307/2297852
Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (2001). Special Interest Politics. MIT Press: Cambridge.
Herman, E., & Chomsky, N. (1998). Manufacturing Consent: The Political Economy of the Mass Media. Pantheon Books: New York.
Hill, M., Kelly, W., Lockhart, B., & Van Ness, R. (2013). Determinants and effects of corporate lobbying. Financial Management, 42(4), 931-957. doi. 10.1111/fima.12032
Hill, M., Merica, D., & Zeleny, J. (2016). Bernie Sanders Endorses Hilary Clinton. July 12. [Retrieved from].
Huber, G.., & Arceneuaux, K. (2007). Identifying the persuasive effects of presidential advertising. American Journal of Political Science, 51(4), 957-977. doi. 10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00291.x
Jacobsen, L. (2016). Bernie Sanders says he consistently beats Trump by a Larger Margin than Clinton. PolitiFacts, March 8. [Retrieved from].
Kawai, K., & Watanabe, Y. (2013). Inferring strategic voting. American Economic Review, 103(2), 624-662. doi. 10.1257/aer.103.2.624
Klandermans, P. (2014). Identity politics and polartiticized identities: Identity processes and the dynamics of protest. Political Psychology, 35(1), 1-22. doi. 10.1111/pops.12167
Kutler, J. (2019). Oliver Wyman to investment banks: Go greenfield. GARP, February 1. [Retrieved from].
Le Conte, M. (2018). Twitter bots can make opinions more extreme. NewScientist, April 7. p.8.
Le Miere, J. (2017). Bernie Sanders voters helped Trump win the election and here's proof. Newsweek, August 23. [Retrieved from].
Levitt. S (1994). Using repeat challengers to estimate the impact of campaign spending on election outcomes. Journal of Political Economy, 102(4), 777-798. doi. 10.1086/261954
Meunier, S. (2017). The French presidency is a bargain. TheWorldPost, [Retrieved from].
Murphy, A. (2019). A model of optimizing political expenditures to buy government power. Economic and Political Studies (2019 forthcoming).
Myatt, D. (2015). A theory of protest voting. Economic Journal, 127(603), 1527-1567. doi. 10.1111/ecoj.12333
Myersen, R., & Weber, R. (1993). A theory of voting equilibria. American Political Science Review, 87(1), 102-114. doi. 10.2307/2938959
Negin, E. (2016). Exxon-mobil is continuing to fund climate science deniers. Huffpost, July 14. [Retrieved from].
OpenSecrets.org. (2016). 2016 presidential race. [Retrieved from].
Passarelli, F., & Tabellini, G. (2017). Emotions and political unrest. Journal of Political Economy, 125(3), 903-946. doi. 10.1086/691700
Peeters, R., Saran, R., & Yueksel, A. (2016). Strategic party formation on a circle and Durverger's Law. Social Choice and Welfare, 47(3), 729-759. doi. 10.1007/s00355-016-0990-z
Pietryka, M., & DeBats, D. (2017). It's not just what you have, but who you know: Networks, social proximity to elites, and voting in state and local elections. American Political Science Review, 111(2), 360-378. doi. 10.1017/S000305541600071X
Pons, V., & Tricaud, C. (2018). Expressive voting and its cost: Evidence from runoffs with two or three candidates. Econometrica, 86(5),1621-1649. doi. 10.3982/ECTA15373
Ryan, R., & Deci, E. (2001). On happiness and human potentials: A review of reseach on hedonic and eudaimonic well-being. Annual Review of Psychology, 52, 141-166. doi. 10.1146/annurev.psych.52.1.141
Schickler, E. (2016). Radical Realignment: The Transformation of American Liberalism, 1932-1965. Princeton University Press: Princeton.
Shayo, M., & Harel, A. (2012). Non-consequentialist voting. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81(1), 299-313. doi. 10.1016/j.jebo.2011.10.021
Shin, J. (2016). The consequence of government ideology and taxation on welfare voting. Political Science Quarterly, 69(3), 430-443. doi. 10.1177/1065912916648014
Spinney, L. (2017). Culture clash. NewScientist, April 7. 37-39.
Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5(3), 224-232. doi. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.1967.tb01923.x
von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1953). Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Wang, H., & Qian, C. (2012). Corporate philanthropy and firm financial performance: The roles of shareholder response and political access. Academy of Management, 54(6), 1159-1181. doi. 10.5465/amj.2009.0548
270ToWin. (2017a). 2016 Margin of Victory Map. March 21. [Retrieved from].
270ToWin. (2017b). 2016 Election: Sanders vs. Trump. July 7. [Retrieved from].