Abstract
Abstract. The article examines the use of discretionary production by key OPEC members to protect the long-term value of their reserves. Although interpretations vary on its behaviour and market power, the organisation sees its role as promoting the security of supply through stabilising markets while protecting market share and ensuring a fair return to capital. Given the new and perennial challenges facing its members, there are diverse views on how these policy objectives may be promoted. Using option theory, we argue that the market stabilisation policy of OPEC in effect, provides free risk management to the global market and conflicts fundamentally with its long-term objective of protecting market share through discouraging high-cost marginal producers. Abandoning this policy, the returns to marginal producers, adjusted for risk, would be reduced. As implications of our research, rather than creating a social good through mitigating price risk, OPEC should allow markets to be volatile and even consider using its discretionary buffer in a pro-cyclic manner, to protect the long-term value of its reserves.
Keywords. OPEC, Risk Management, Shale Petroleum.
JEL. Q02, Q43, Q48, Q58.References
Alhajjia, A.F. & Huettnerb, D., (2000). OPEC and other commodity cartels: a comparison, Energy Policy, 28(15), 1151-1164. doi. 10.1016/S0301-4215(00)00095-1
Adelman, M. (1972). The World Petroleum Market, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Alkhathlan, K., Gatley, D., & Javid, M. (2014). Analysis of Saudi Arabia's behavior within OPEC and the world oil market, Energy Policy, 64, 209-225. doi. 10.1016/j.enpol.2013.09.030
Asanoa, T., & Shibatab, A. (2011). Optimal pricing and quality choice of a monopolist under Knightian uncertainty, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 29(6), 746-754. doi. 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2011.04.002
Barnett, J., & Dessai, S. (2004). Will OPEC lose from the Kyoto Protocol?, Energy Policy, 32(18), 2077-2088. doi. 10.1016/S0301-4215(03)00183-6
Blas, J., & Carroll J. (2016). Saudi Arabia to U.S. Oilmen: Cut Costs or Exit the Business, Bloomberg, 23-2-2016. [Retrieved from].
Bloomberg News, (2016). News, February 16, 2016. [Retrieved from].
Cairns, R., & Calfucura, E. (2012). OPEC: Market failure or power failure?, Energy Policy, 50, 570-580. doi. 10.1016/j.enpol.2012.07.058
Campbell, C., & Laherrère, J.H. (1998). The end of cheap oil, Scientific American, 278(3), 78-84.
Flowers, S. (2018). Future cost of new oil supply: shale vs conventional Implications of tight oil’s hegemony, Wood Mackenzie. [Retrieved from].
Goldstein, W.(1983). Can OPEC survive 1984?, Energy Policy, 11(3), 196-203. doi. 10.1016/0301-4215(83)90076-9
Gulf Cooperation Council (2018). [Retrieved from].
Horn, M. (2000). OPEC's optimal crude oil price, Energy Policy, 32(2), 269-280. doi. 10.1016/S0301-4215(02)00289-6
Hull, J. (2012). Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, Pearson University Press.
International Monetary Fund. (2017). Middle East and Central Asia Dept. Saudi Arabia: 2017 Article IV Consultation-Press Release; and Staff Report, Country Report, No.17/316. [Retrieved from].
Jefferson, M. (2012). Shell scenarios: What really happened in the 1970s and what may be learned for current world prospects, Journal of Technological Forecasting & Social Change, 79(1), 186-197. doi. 10.1016/j.techfore.2011.08.007
Kisswani, K.M. (2016). Does OPEC act as a cartel? Empirical investigation of coordination behaviour, Energy Policy, 97, 171-180. doi. 10.1016/j.enpol.2016.07.013
Korybko, A. (2017). Is Saudi Arabia’s Grand Strategy Shifting?, Oriental Review, 06/10/2017. [Retrieved from].
Kunreuther, H., Onculer, A., & Slovic, P. (1998). Time insensitivity for protective investments, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 16(3), 279–299. doi. 10.1023/A:1007759120746
Léautier, T., & Rochet, J. (2014). On the strategic value of risk management, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 37, 153-169. doi. 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2014.07.006
Loutia, A.C. Mellios, C., & Andriosopoulos, K. (2016). Do OPEC announcements influence oil prices?, Energy Policy, 90, 262-272. doi. 10.1016/j.enpol.2015.11.025
MacFadyen, A.J. (1993). OPEC and cheating: Revisiting the kinked demand curve, Energy Policy, 21(8), 858-867. doi. 10.1016/0301-4215(93)90170-K
MacKay, P., & Moeller, S.B. (2007). The value of corporate risk management, Journal of Finance, 62(3), 1379-1419. doi. 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2007.01239.x
Pierru, A.J., Smith, L., & Zamrik, T. (2017). OPEC’s impact on oil price volatility: The role of spare capacity, The Energy Journal, 39(2), 173-196. doi. 10.5547/01956574.39.2.apie
Petroleum Economist, (2005). Saudi’s Al-Naimi: deliverability, not availability is oil’s problem. [Retrieved from].
Petroleum Economist, (2012), Saudi Arabia remains the supply-side optimist. [Retrieved from].
Petroleum Economist, (2016). [Retrieved from].
Petroleum Economist, (2018). [Retrieved from].
Raval, A.(19-3-2018), Saudi Arabia wrestles with oil price dilemma as existential crisis returns, Financial Times, p.25. [Retrieved from].
Raval, A., (2018). Opec and Russia considering 10-20-year oil alliance, Financial Times. [Retrieved from].
Reynolds, D.B. (1999). Modeling OPEC behavior: theories of risk aversion for oil producer decisions, Energy Policy, 27(15), 901-912. doi. 10.1016/S0301-4215(99)00076-2
Reynolds, D.B., & Pippenger, M.K. (2010). OPEC and Venezuelan oil production: Evidence against a cartel hypothesis, Energy Policy, 38(10), 6045-6055. doi. 10.1016/j.enpol.2010.05.060
Rothschild, R. (1999). Cartel stability when costs are heterogeneous, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 17(5), 717-734. doi. 10.1016/S0167-7187(97)00052-0
Samuelson, P.A. (1937). A note on measurement of utility, Review of Economic Studies, 4(2), 155–161. doi. 10.2307/2967612
Simmons, M. (2005), Twilight in the Desert: The Coming Saudi Oil Shock and the World Economy Hardcover, New York, New York: John Wiley & Son.
Tufano, P. (1996). Who manages risk, Journal of Finance, 51(4), 1097-1137. doi. 10.2307/2329389
Yergin, D. (1990). The Prize, New York, New York: Simon & Schuster.