Abstract
Abstract. In the field of philosophy of mind, the concepts of rational behavior, rational choice theory, and instrumental rationality (the “practical reasoning” version of rationality) are important in trying to make statements and conclusions about human thinking and behavior in general. Rational choice theory is also considered a normative but not a descriptive or positive theory. Much of economic theory is based on the principle that economic agents usually or always behave rationally in maximizing the benefits and/or minimizing the costs of their decisions. Developments in behavioral economics over the last several decades have begun to question this principle with much of the questioning about rationality and rational behavior centering on whether individuals can correctly and adequately assess probabilities and risk/reward. The inability to correctly assess risk/reward limits rational behavior and can yield sub-optimal outcomes for economic agents. This exploratory paper examines the linkages between schooling in a capitalist society and limits on rationality in a monopoly capital economic system.
Keywords. Behavioral economics, Capitalist schooling, Monopoly capital, Rationality, Rational choice.
JEL. B51, I24.References
Baran, P.A., & Sweezy, P.M. (1966). Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the American Economic and Social Order. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Barberis, N.C. (2013). Thirty years of prospect theory in economics: A review and assessment, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27(1), 173-196. doi. .10.1257/jep.27.1.173
Booij, A.S., van Praag, B.M.S., & van de Kuilen, G. (2009). A parametric analysis of prospect theory's functionals for the general population. Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor, Discussion Paper Series, April 2009. [Retrieved from].
Brette, O., Lazaric, N., & da Silva, V.V. (2017). Habit, decision-making, and rationality. Journal of Economic Issues, 51(3), 567-587. doi. 10.1080/00213624.2017.1353866
Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (1976). Schooling in Capitalist America. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (2002). Schooling in capitalist America revisited, Sociology of Education, 75(1), 1-18. doi. 10.2307/3090251
Clark, W.A.V., & Lisowski, W. (2017). Prospect theory and the decision to stay or move. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, United States of America. Accessed on December 8, 2018. [Retrieved from].
Cordes, C. (2005). Veblen’s instinct of workmanship, its cognitive foundations, and some implications for economic theory. Journal of Economic Issues, 49(1), 1-20. doi. 10.1080/00213624.2005.11506778
Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (1994). Better than rational: Evolutionary psychology and the invisible hand. American Economic Review, 84(2), 327-332.
Evans, J.St.B.T. (2014). Two minds rationality. Thinking and Reasoning, 20(2), 129-146. doi. 10.1080/13546783.2013.845605
Gächter, S., Johnson, E.J., & Herrmann, A. (2007). Individual-level loss aversion in riskless and risky choices. Institute for the Study of Labor, IZA Discussion Paper, No.2960. Accessed on December 9, 2018. [Retrieved from].
Jaworski, W. (2011). Philosophy of Mind: A Comprehensive Introduction. Chichester, West Sussex, UK: John Wiley and Sons, Ltd.
Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics, American Economic Review, 93(5), 1449-1475. doi. 10.1257/000282803322655392
Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York, NY: Farrar, Straus, and Giroux Publishers.
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk, Econometrica, 47(2), 263-291. doi. 10.2307/1914185
Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (1982). Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Keynes, J.M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. New York, NY: Harcourt, Brace and Company. First Published: Macmillan Cambridge University Press.
Kim, H., Kim, B., Syngioo, C., Booyuel, K., & Pop-Eleches; C. (2018). The role of education interventions in improving economic rationality. Science, 362(6410), 83-86. doi. 10.1126/science.aar6987
Lee, F.S. (2009). The emergence of heterodox economics, 1990 – 2006. From the Association of Heterodox Economics website, Accessed on December 9, 2018. [Retrieved from].
Markey-Towler, B. (2017). I, roboticus oeconomicus. The philosophy of mind in economics and why it matters. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 41(1), 200-237. doi. 10.1093/cje/bew014
Marnet, O. (2005). Behavior and rationality in corporate governance, Journal of Economic Issues, 39(3), 613-632. doi. 10.1080/00213624.2005.11506837
Marx, K., & Engels, F. (1932). The German ideology. Accessed on December 8, 2018. [Retrieved from].
MIT Dictionary of Modern Economics, 3rd Edition. (1989). Edited by David W. Pearce. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Nicholson, W. (1989). Microeconomic Theory: Basic Principles and Extensions, 4th Edition. Chicago, IL: The Dryden Press.
O'Connor, J. (1973). The Fiscal Crisis of the State. New York: St. Martin's Press.
Pressman, S. (2006). Kahneman, Tversky and institutional economics. Journal of Economic Issues, 50(2), 501-506. doi. 10.1080/00213624.2006.11506929
Samuels, R., Stich, S., & Bishop, M. (2002). Ending the rationality wars: How to make disputes about human rationality disappear. In R. Elio, (Edt.), Common Sense, Reasoning and Rationality. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Sen, A. (1977). Rational fools: A critique of the behavioral foundations of economic theory. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 6(4), 317-344.
Simon, H.A. (1978). Rationality as process and as product of thought. American Economic Review, 68(2), 1-16.
Simon, H.A. (1997). Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organizations (4th ed.). New York, NY: Free Press.
Sloman, S.A., Over, D., Slovak, L., & Stibel, J.M. (2003). Frequency illusions and other fallacies. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Process, 91(2), 296-309. doi. 10.1016/S0749-5978(03)00021-9
Smith, A. (2000). The Wealth of Nations. Introduction by Robert Reich. New York, NY: Modern Library,
Smith, T.W., Michael, D., Jeremy, F., & Hout, M. -General Social Surveys-, (1972-2016). [machine-readable data file] /Principal Investigator, Smith, Tom W.; Co-Principal Investigators, Peter V. Marsden and Michael Hout; Sponsored by National Science Foundation. --NORC ed.-- Chicago: NORC, 2018: NORC at the University of Chicago [producer and distributor]. Data accessed from the GSS Data Explorer. [Retrieved from].
Sturm, T. (2012). The ‘rationality wars’ in psychology: Where they are and where they could go. Inquiry, 55(1), 66-81. doi. 10.1080/0020174X.2012.643628
Thaler, R.H. (2015). Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioral Economics. New York, NY: W. W. Norton & Company.
U.S. Department of Education, Institute of Education Sciences, National Center for Education Statistics. (2005, 2009, 2013, and 2015). National Assessment of Educational Progress (NAEP), 2005, 2009, 2013, and 2015 Mathematics Assessments. Accessed on March 4, 2019. [Retrieved from].
Varian, H.R. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd Edition. New York, NY: W.W. Norton and Company.
Wolozin, H. (2004). The human mind, institutions, and economic behavior. Journal of Economic Issues, 38(2), 563-570. doi. 10.1080/00213624.2004.11506718
Yilmaz, F. (2007). Veblen and the problem of rationality. Journal of Economic Issues, 41(3), 841-862. doi. 10.1080/00213624.2007.11507064